Skip to main content

NGO COUP



Its clear that NGOs have become a force onto themselves. At any given moment, at any part of the world, a NGO is probably engaging citizens to take part in some form of group activity. These group meetings are considered essential tools for social change. Almost all of the time, participation is voluntary, meaning people are not paid for the one or two hours of their time to take part in the meeting. Add up the citizen hours of people engaged in water groups, forestry groups, women’s groups, VDC groups, health groups, men’s groups—and you end up getting a very large chunk of productive time being given over to the activities of NGOs and their programs. The funding comes from INGOs, who use small block grants of $1000 to these groups to entice participation.

Now the question arises: does it economically make sense for a country’s citizen to spend this much time in voluntary group activities? And how much time do they lose from a day in which they could be earning money in already hard-pressed circumstances? And how coercive are these groups, and how do they assert pressure on group members to come and participate—despite the fact the person at the other end may not have the time for these activities?

Time of course is money, not just in the West but also in developing countries. But somehow those who run international organizations seem convinced that the “target groups” should give them their time for free—including for repeated interviews about the same conflict violations they may have faced, the same focus group discussions, the same lengthy meetings about women’s empowerment. 

On the one hand, these meetings show results. Clearly people are more “empowered” because of them. On the other hand, it begs the question: if Western countries have the power to extract resources from poor people and pay them very little for it, is there a level of irony in having INGOs from these very same countries come and save the people who are being materially and financially exploited by corporations, financial entities, and other institutions that keep poverty at the same level it is now? In other words, do the  farmers of poor countries get exploited twice—first by having their products taken by rich local elites at such cheap prices the  farmer may never get out of debt, and then secondly by being put in groups and “social changed” by the very same countries which exploit and consume these resources? 

Is there something strange about this arrangement? 

It appears Uganda has just passed a law demanding greater scrutiny of NGO funding and activities. The truth of the matter is: developing countries have no idea, on an official level, what the NGOs on their soil are up to, what funding they receive, how much of it and from what sources, for what purposes, and what programmatic goals. Are these programs replicating or replacing government activities? Are they debilitating the government by making it redundant, and therefore useless? Which, if you come to think about it, is another “soft power” way to rule in the old Colonial manner. If the government comes to be seen as useless, because almost all government activities are being conducted by NGOs, I would call that a post-colonial coup, in all senses of the term. 

Are people really looking at the scale of NGO operations around the world, and questioning what these presence has done to weaken governments and countries in poorer parts of the world?




Comments

Popular posts from this blog

The Bitter Truth: Talat Abbasi's Bitter Gourds

The stories are small, but with a spicy aftertaste that could be from nowhere else but the subcontinent. Talat Abbasi's Bitter Gourd and Other Stories is a collection of nugget sized, delectable tales laid out, in typical desi fashion, amongst the detritus of social stratification, family ennui, economic marginalization and diaspora. Gently dousing her stories with a generous portion of irony and satire, the Karachi born writer brings to the fore the small hypocrisies and the mundane corruptions of everyday life in Pakistan. Whether dealing with a birdman or a poor relation, a rich widow or an immigrant mother, Ms. Abbasi touches the mythic heart that ticks besides all these caricatures. The ghostly narrative influence of Virginia Woolf, with a pinch of Victorian lit thrown in for good measure, is discernable, although most of the voices are centered around the "how kind, how kind" echoes of South Asia. The book starts, appropriately, with a story about a feudal patro

INTERVIEW: TOM ARENS

KHULA MANCH Tom Arens first came to Nepal in 1972 as the South Asian representative of World Neighbors, a small American INGO. He stayed for 28 years. He was one of the founding members of the Federation of NGOs. Arens talked with Sushma Joshi of the Nation Weekly about the changes he has seen in the development scene in Nepal, as well as his thoughts about the direction in which the nation should take in the coming years. What was Nepal like in 1972? When World Neighbors first started, we worked with The Nepal’s Women’s Organization and Paropakar. These were the only two established smaller NGOs. We started with small funds: $50,000-100,000 the first couple of years. The government was ambivalent about smaller non-profits, so we couldn’t get registered until 7 years later, when the Social Service Welfare Council was established. The Queen was the chair. The Council helped to give status to smaller non-profits and to facilitate our work. What was your first program? Our first program w

Milk and rice

Sushma Joshi I am the youngest of seven cousins. When we were little, we used to play lukamari , or hide-and-seek, games in the garden. My eldest cousin sister, taking pity on me, would allow me to be a dudh-bhat (milk and rice) during our games. A dudh-bhat is someone too young to play the game adequately, but the older children allow this young one to tag along and never be “outed” from the game because they might cry if made to leave. So this means you are endlessly in the game, even when in reality you should really be out. Of course, being the youngest means you may always retain the status of a dudh-bhat even when you do grow up. In Nepal, as we know all too well, the hierarchy of age allows the young some privileges, along with the old. It appears to me Madhav Kumar, even though he's lost the game twice in two elections, is being allowed to be the dudh-bhat by his wiser and more tolerant elders. He is allowed to be in the game endlessly even though in reality he should real